-
Drug Regulation and Pricing
N Engl J Med 2016; 374:1807-1809
Can Regulators Influence Affordability?
Public debate in the 1990s over drugs’ clinical toxicity has given way to concerns about their financial toxicity. Although drug regulators aren’t supposed to be concerned with pricing, they’ve been drawn into an acrimonious debate over the cost of medicines.
At the European Medicines Agency (EMA), we often hear conflicting arguments: high and inflexible regulatory standards drive up the cost of pharmaceutical research and development (R&D), thereby increasing drug prices; regulators license products even when the data are insufficient for assessing their value and allow drug makers to overcharge; more generics, biosimilars, and me-too drugs are needed to create a dynamic market that will keep prices down; me-too drugs should be discouraged, since they offer no added benefit to patients and lead to overutilization and higher spending; and regulators shouldn’t allow drugs on the market that no one can afford.
So are regulators responsible for high drug prices? The short answer is yes and no. Before drug regulatory agencies existed, all sorts of “remedies” were sold on street corners — sometimes for a penny. But even if high prices weren’t always an issue, concerns about product quality, safety, and lack of efficacy created a need for regulation. In the ensuing decades, regulatory agencies have developed sophisticated evidence standards to ensure that approved drugs have favorable benefit–risk profiles. Regulators have, for example, developed rigorous standards for the generation and analysis of clinical trial data and for acceptable trial end points and study designs. Regulatory requirements have undoubtedly made pharmaceutical R&D expensive.
At the same time, a regulatory seal of approval is the most important distinguishing factor that allows drug developers to charge high prices for products. Without evidence that has been vetted by regulators, why would anyone pay more for any drug than they would for, say, a dietary supplement? If we eliminated regulation, the current biopharmaceutical business model would collapse — and so would science-based drug development. Without a requirement for regulatory approval, companies would have no incentive to conduct expensive clinical trials of their products. Lowering regulatory standards would be unwise for both patients and organizations that invest in pharmaceutical R&D. Robust regulation improves public health and creates economic value.
But the fact that regulation drives up R&D costs doesn’t mean it’s the only factor contributing to high prices — or even the most important one. Nor can we conclude the converse — that if only the high cost of R&D (driven by regulations) could be reduced, then prices would automatically drop. Even pharmaceutical executives admit that this assumption is naive; companies tend to charge whatever the market will bear. Any belief in a correlation between R&D costs and market price was dispelled during the recent debate over the price of the new hepatitis C drug Sovaldi.
Regulators should not, for the sake of affordability, yield to pressure to lower standards. But it’s also inappropriate for them to be oblivious to the growing budget pains caused by newly authorized products. We believe there are several ways regulators can contribute to keeping drug spending sustainable, at least in the European Union (EU). (We recognize that some of these steps may not be readily implementable in the United States, owing to its legislative framework.)
First, by rapidly approving generics and biosimilars and allowing them to enter the market once patents or exclusivity periods have expired, regulators can facilitate competition, which drives down prices. Regulators could, for example, fast-track additional generic authorizations when companies are taking advantage of monopoly conditions for generic drugs.
Second, regulators can work to ensure that me-too products continue to come on the market at a reasonable speed. Some consumer advocates lament the high proportion of me-too products that provide limited or no added value over available drugs. But added value is difficult to predict, and some me-too products that were originally criticized have benefited patients and provided additional treatment options. More important, sometimes the availability of these products can drive down prices almost as much as the availability of generics. When hepatitis C medications similar to Sovaldi entered the market, for example, prices were reduced and access to treatment broadened.
Third, regulators can encourage clinical trials that measure value. Payers need data that enable them to assess value in order to determine how much they should pay for a given drug. Health technology assessment (HTA) bodies that advise payers say that the clinical trials supporting marketing authorization often fall short in providing such data. The additional information required may relate to, for example, measures of quality of life or health care resource utilization. To bridge this gap, the EMA, and some EU member states, have been hosting “parallel scientific advice” sessions at which regulators, HTA experts, and drug developers discuss premarketing clinical trial designs. Experience from nearly 70 of these sessions shows that studies can generally be designed to satisfy the needs of regulatory decision makers and support demonstration of value to payers.
Fourth, regulators can facilitate collection of other kinds of data that are important to payers. Increasingly, payers and pharmaceutical companies are considering outcome-focused deals tying a drug’s price to the results achieved. Although pay-for-performance schemes are attractive in theory, practical hurdles have prevented widespread adoption. Most important is the difficulty of collecting and interpreting the relevant patient-level data in a given health care system. Regulators, at least in some countries, can facilitate data collection by considering payers’ needs when asking companies to conduct postapproval studies. In at least one case, a company was able to piggyback an outcomes-based scheme on processes already in place to monitor a drug’s safety. The EMA is now exploring with HTA bodies ways to collaborate on registries or other forms of postapproval evidence generation to achieve these dual goals.
It’s clear that in the future, the market will not bear some of the higher drug prices that are being fetched today. One implication for public health is that potentially useful products may not be developed if companies fear they won’t be able to recoup their R&D costs. When prices are squeezed, improving R&D efficiency will become even more important than it is today. How can regulators help achieve this goal?
Clinical drug development is generally an inefficient process. The cost of conducting clinical trials drives R&D spending, and much of the elaborate superstructure involved needs to be reassessed and could be pared down without harming participants. The EMA actively promotes better design and more efficient trial conduct4 and supports the efforts of the Clinical Trials Transformation Initiative, created by the Food and Drug Administration and Duke University, and other efforts to streamline trials.
Similarly, conventional development and licensing pathways are often economically inefficient. Working with HTA bodies and patient groups, the EMA is exploring whether a more flexible development, licensing, and reimbursement approach called adaptive pathways may help companies stagger clinical development costs, generate revenue earlier, and remove some risk from R&D without relaxing the criteria for determining products’ risk–benefit profiles.5 We expect that this kind of “life span” approach to generating evidence — with more targeted selection of trial participants, managed growth of the treatment-eligible population, and full use of postlicensing Risk Management Plans (EU) or Risk Evaluation and Mitigation Strategies (United States) — will lower the threshold for financing drug development at a time when prices are coming under pressure.
We firmly believe that assessment of quality, safety, and efficacy should remain separate from pricing and reimbursement decisions. Regulators alone cannot solve the growing problem of high drug prices. We understand that new drugs should command prices that reward and provide incentives for R&D investment. However, we fail to comprehend prices that, like Sovaldi’s, recoup the entire investment within the first few months after a product’s launch but are so unaffordable that patients in need are denied access. We are committed to doing our part to facilitate continued access to effective and safe treatments.
-
Articoli correlati
2permille, 5permille, 8permille, accumulazione, acel, acqua, acquirente unico, adapt, addetti, adeguatezza, adequacy of income, aeeg, agcm, age divide, aging, agricoltura, agsi, ai, aifa, almalaurea, ammortizzatori, ammortizzatori sociali, anac, anpal, ape, appalti, archivio, area euro, arera, arrow, arte, article iv, articolo 18, artificial intelligence, asili nido, assegno di ricollocazione, assicurazione, assistenza, aste, astrid, attivazioni & cessazioni, au, austerità, autonomia, awg, baby boomers, banca centrale, banca d'italia, basic income, basilicata, bce, behavioural economics, benchmark sanitari, benchmarking, benchmarking sanitario, benzina, berlin-washington consensus, bersani, beveridge, bicameralismo, big data, bilancio, bilateralità, biosimilari, biotecnologie, bismarck, bocconi, boeri, bonus renzi, brevetti, brevetto, brexit, bruegel, budget process, calabria, calcolo contributivo, calcolo retributivo, calderoli, camera dei deputati, campagna, campania, capitale cultura, capitale umano, carbone, casa, casa&immobili, cash, cassa integrazione, catalogna, cbo, ce, cesifo, chiesa, cig, cigo, cigs, cina, cingolani, città metropolitane, cittadinanza, clinical trials, coal, codice dei contratti, commercio, commissione cassese, commissione onofri, competitività, comuni, comunicazioni obbligatorie, concorrenza, congiuntura, consumo, contante, conti nazionali, contoannuale, contributo perequativo, convegni e dibattiti, cooperazione, copay, coronavirus, corridoi europei, corte costituzionale, corte dei conti, corte di cassazione, corte di giustizia europea, costituzione, costruzioni, covid-19, covid19, covip, crescita, crisi a confronto, crisi economica, croce, ctfs, cultura, cuneo sul lavoro, damiano, davide colombo, day hospital, dcf economics, debito, debito pubblico, decentramento, decontribuzione, decreto dignità, def, deficit, deflazione, democrazia, democrazia diretta, demografia, demography, dependency ratio, dg energy, diesel, dimensione, dipendenti pubblici, dipendenza strutturale, diritti acquisiti, diritti civili, diritti umani, diritto, diritto costituzionale, diritto ecclesiastico, diritto internazionale, disability, disegno istituzionale, disoccupazione, dispositivi medici, distribuzione del farmaco, distribuzione del reddito, disuguaglianze, divario nord-sud, documentazione, draghi, dual tax, dualismo territoriale, ecb, ecofin, economia comportamentale, economia italiana, economia&architettura, economia&diritto, economia&letteratura, economia&storia, education, efficientamento della pa, eiopa, elderly, elders, elezioni, elezioni 2022, ema, emigrazione, emilia romagna, energia, energy, eni, environment, epl, equità, equivalenti, eredità&donazioni, espanet, esrb, esspros, esternalità, etica&economia, ets, euro, eurobarometro, eurobond, europa, europe, europe-us, european commission, european fiscal board, europei, eurostat, eurozona, evasione, evidence-based-policy, fabbisogni standard, famiglie, farmacie, farmacoeconomia, farmaref, federalismo, federalismo fiscale, fesr, filosofia, financial statistics, finanza pubblica, finland, firma digitale, fis, fiscal compact, fiscal rules, fiscalità, flat tax, foi, fondazione einaudi, fondi pensione, fondi sanitari, fondi welfare, fondo di solidarietà comunale, food tax, fornero, francia, friedman, fsc, fund raising, gare, gas, gasolio, generational divide, generazioni, generici, gentile, geografia economica, geopolitica, germania, giovani, global agewatch index, globalizzazione, gme, going for growth, google trends, gran bretagna, grandi opere, grecia, greece, green pass, grexit, growth, gse, health care, households, housing, hta, human capital, ia, ilsole24ore, imf, immigrazione, impact assessment, imprese, in-kind welfare, in-silico, incentivi, incentivo maroni, india, indicizzazione, industria, inequality, inflazione, infrastrutture, innovation, innovazione, inpdap, inps, inquinamento, insegnanti, internet, invecchiamento, investimenti, ipca, iri, irpef, irpet, isee, islam, iso, istat, istituzioni, it-silc, italia-domani, iue, iva, jaspers, job act, jobs act, kant, karlsruhe, kela, keynes, la buona scuola, laffer, lagarde, lavorareinfo, lavori pubblici, lavoro, lavoro nero, law&economics, lazio, ldi, lea, legge annuale per il mercato e la concorrenza, legge bilancio, legge di bilancio, legge di stabilità, legge elettorale, lep, letteratura, liberalizzazioni, libere professioni, licenziamento collettivo, licenziamento individuale, liguria, llf, lombardia, ltc, lump of labor, m5s, mantoux, marche, marianna mazzucato, marshall, matera, mattarellum, mattei, media, mediooriente, mediterraneo, mefop, mental accounting, mercati finanziari, mercato, mercato del lavoro, meritocrazia, merkel, mes, messina, mezzogiorno, microsimulation, microsimulazione, migrazioni, mimit, mip, miscellanea, mobilità, moneta, moneta digitale, monopolio, monti, mortalità, multipilastro, multipillar, naspi, nato, nber, net pensions, net social expenditure, netflix, nexi, next generation eu, nfa, ngeu, nice, nitti, nobel, nucleare, nudging, obama, obblighi di cittadinanza, occupati, occupazione, ocse, oecd, oecd italy fiche, off-patent, oil, old age, omt, onofri, optimal taxation, optimellum, opzione donna, ordini professionali, ortodossia, osmed, osservatori inps, osservatorio adapt, outlook, output gap, pace, pagamenti elettronici, palestina, panel estimation, parafarmacie, pareggio di bilancio, parlamento, patent, patent-box, patrimonio, patto della salute, patto di stabilità, pay-as-you-go, pay-back, payback, pensionamento flessibile, pensione di cittadinanza, pensioni, pensions, pepp, perequazione, petrolio, pharmaceuticals, piani di rientro, piano juncker, piemonte, pil, pil potenziale, pisa, plastic tax, pnrr, politica, politica & storia, politica industriale, politica internazionale, politica monetaria, political economy, politiche attive del lavoro, politiche passive del lavoro, politics, ponte sullo stretto, population, pos, potenza, povertà, poverty, pressione fiscale, previdenza, previdenza complementare, prezzi, prezzo petrolio, pricing, prima guerra mondiale, primarie, primo pilastro, privatizzazioni, procurement, productivity, produttività, produzione industriale, progetto galileo, progetto mappatura ssr, programma di stabilità, programmi di stabilità, progressività, proiezioni, proiezioni di spesa, projections, propensity score matching, proprietà intellettuale, province, pubblica amministrazione, pubblico impiego, public choice, public debt, public economics, public finances, public procurement, puglia, qe, qualità della spesa, qualità delle norme, quest model, quota 100, quota 102, quota 103, r&d, r&s, ragioneria generale dello stato, react eu, recovery and resilience facility, recovery fund, reddito di cittadinanza, redistribuzione, reference pricing, referendum, reggio calabria, regioni, regions, regis, regolazione, rei, relativismo, repository, repower eu, reputation & expectations, residui fiscali, retail commerce, rete, retirement, rfl, rgs, riciclaggio, riforma amato, riforma dello stato, riforma dini, riforma fondiaria, riforma fornero, riforme strutturali, rinnovabili, ripartizione, ripresa, rischio, risparmio, rita, rlf, robotica, rosatellum, rpl, rubrica radio, russia, saldo strutturale, salute pubblica, salvaguardie, sandel, saniref, sanità, schrodinger, scienza delle finanze, scozia, scuola, scuola superiore sant'anna pisa, seconda guerra mondiale, secondo pilastro, self-defeating policy, semplificazione amministrativa, sen, senato, serie storiche, servizi, servizio universale, sespros, severance pay, sicilia, sindacati, sistema delle conferenze, sistema sanitario, sistema sociale, sistemi sanitari, sky-q, snam, social, social exclusion, social expenditure, solvency ii, sommerso&evasione, sose, sostenibilità, sovranismi, spagna, spazio, spending review, spesa farmaceutica, spesa per istruzione, spesa sanitaria, spesa sociale, spid, ssn, ssr, sssup, stacco carburante, staffetta generazionale, standard sanitari, stati uniti, statistics, statuto dei lavoratori, statuto speciale, stazioni appaltanti, stem, storia, strade, stress test, structural balance, structural reforms, sud, sugar tax, superbonus, sure, survivors, sustainability, sviluppo, svimez, tableau, tap, tar, target-2, tasi, tassazione, tasse pigouviane, tassi di interesse, tax burden, tax expenditure, tax-deferral, tax-expenditure, taxing wages, ted, telecomunicazioni, teoria economica, teorie economiche, terna, tfr, tfs, thaler, titoli sovrani, titolo v, toscana, trading deregulation, transizione digit, transizione ecologica, transizione green, transizione università-lavoro, trasporti, trattati di roma, trattato di lisbona, trentino alto adige, trickle-down, trips, trivelle, troika, trump, tunisia, tutele crescenti, ucraina, ufficio parlamentare di bilancio, uk, ula, umbria, unconventional qe, undp, unemployment, unemployment benefits, unione europea, unione fiscale, unione monetaria, universal service, universalismo, universalismo selettivo, università, upb, us, us census bureau, vaccinazione, vaccino, varie, veneto, versailles, via della seta, voto, voucher, welfare, welfare fiscale, wellbeing, wellbeing of older people, who, youngsters, zero interest rate policy